Without question, bubbles run out
of control and all the related mechanisms are promoted in place to cause
excessive credit exposure. Here we get a
quick history in which wishful thinking and a laudable aim to place folks in
homes got nudged into overdrive. So
what! Every market once it is in motion
attracts the same forces that normally have hard learned governors in
place. Here the lessons of the thirties
were chucked because of a severe lack of imagination or simply the stupid and
greedy got to call the shots.
A credit pricing rule needs to be
implemented that forces credit granters to tie loan ratios to a five year
average value in the housing and general real-estate industry rather than to
current value as appears to be the present practice. Automatically, in the face of rising prices,
greater equity is necessary and demanded.
As critical, it makes diddling the numbers practically impossible.
Equally important in the face of
dropping prices, the ratios become naturally more generous.
Most important if effectively
blocks spiraling credit granting growing much faster than the real market.
It really is that simple and put
in place; prices will adjust to allow all participants to be treated fairly.
Today, the entire USA housing
market could be shifted upward one hundred percent by taking foreclosure inventory
off the market presently driving downward pressure and allowing present
interest rates to support the price structure.
This has happened in Canada
were there is no significant foreclosure inventory.
The housing boom and bust
by RUSS ROBERTS on APRIL 13, 2011
Here is an updated version of Case-Shiller’s housing index for the
country. (The
source for the updating and the image is The Big Picture and TBP
reader Steve Barry.) It is of course somewhat misleading because there is not a
national housing market. But it does capture factors that affect all housing
markets.
Some people explain the recent 15 years as being caused by “animal
spirits” arguing that if you think prices of an asset will go up, then that
belief can be sufficient to cause a bubble. True, no doubt. But what causes
that belief to take hold. Some people say it’s just random. A fad. The madness
of crowds. Could be. I suspect that the
systematic attempt by federal government policy that began in earnest
in 1995 and ran through the Clinton and Bush II administrations had a lot to do
with it.
The housing boom and bust, part 2
by RUSS ROBERTS on APRIL 13, 2011
In this post,
I suggested that the spike in housing prices starting in 1997was due more to
government housing policy and less to animal spirits or a self-fulfilling
bubble that somehow got started out of the blue.
The picture is from Barry Ritholtz’s blog, The Big Picture.
Barry responds in the comments:
Be wary of squishy thinking.
While its easy to blame Uncle Sam, you need to show the data that
supports that argument — so far, no one has successfully done that. NO ONE.
The much more persuasive case has been made that the combination of
ultra low rates, shadow banking system, corrupt rating agencies, foolish
lenders, irresponsible borrowers and dumb bond fund managers were the primary
causes.
The DATA provides an overwhelming viewpoint of where the Housing boom
and bust came from Barry, I think you’re confusing the subprime crisis with the
housing boom.
They are related but they’re not
the same thing. The Fed’s low interest rates between 2002 and 2004, for
example, did have something to do with the subprime crisis. And artificially
low interest rates did inflate the housing market generally. I don’t think they
had anything to do with housing prices in 1997. And yes, the shadow
banking system had a lot to do with the run-up in prices after 2003 or so. And
yes, there were a lot of dumb, myopic lenders, borrowers and bond-fund
managers. But why did they start getting dumb in 1997.
My other thought is that we don’t have particularly good models of
bubbles, by definition. So when you say there no one has produced the data, I’m
not sure what standard to use to evaluate it. What I think you really meant when
you wrote that was that Fannie and Freddie and the CRA can’t explain why Bear
Stearns and Lehman and a bunch of other cowboy waa-hoos went crazy on MBS. And
you’re right. But that’s not all that I meant by government housing policy.
Here’s the outline of my narrative. Sure, it’s squishy in parts. All
narratives are. Yours, too, I suspect, but I’ll let you make the call on that
one.
The role of government in the housing market goes back decades to the
deductibility of mortgage interest, FDIC insurance, and the creation of Fannie
Mae. But those interventions were done a long time ago and they stayed in place
with minor variations. They weren’t the cause of the crisis. You have to find a
change in government policy. My narrative starts in the early 1990′s. Check
out this
articlefrom 1992. (And don’t worry, even though I’m going to use the
letters “CRA” in consecutive order in what follows, I don’t think the CRA is
the main cause of the subprime crisis. I, like you, blame most of that on
shadow banking. But the CRA has something to do with it…)
It’s about how ACORN and others used provisions of the CRA to get urban
banks to make loans in neighborhoods that hadn’t been receiving loans:
The Philadelphia
banks in the program, Mellon, Continental and Fidelity,, say their experience
shows that a well-structured program can break even in the short run and
promises intangible and financial gains over the long haul. The banks charge
sufficient fees to cover costs and work hard to keep delinquencies and
foreclosures low.
“These are not conventional loans and we make sure that we don’t lose
money,” Mr. Desiderio said. “But they are totally beneficial to us because they
improve our trade area. In the long run this will drop to the bottom line.”
Bankers believe that as poor neighborhoods stabilize, the entire region
benefits, which affects a bank’s future profitability.
What is more, these mortgages help banks fulfill somewhat vague
obligations of the Community Reinvestment Act of 1977, which requires banks to
invest in communities that provide them with deposits.
It also talks about the role of Fannie and Freddie. Remember, this is
1992, right around the time HUD starts pushing Fannie and Freddie to buy more
loans than they had bought before in poor neighborhoods.
But the mergers that have helped create the lending programs are also a
cause of concern for some. LaVerne Butts, a Philadelphia Acorn official, fears
that mega-mergers may leave the poor in the dust. “Where’s the accountability?”
she asked. “We’re doing wonderful things, but we’re still swimming against the
tide. Many of these banks still don’t view low- and moderate-income people as
people. When they get so big, who do you lean on?” Aiming at Secondary Market
Yet at present, the three Philadelphia
banks seem responsive. They have lobbied with Acorn in Washington to find ways to make it easier to
package these mortgages and sell them in the secondary market. This would
reduce the banks’ risk and free up more money to lend.
The biggest buyer of mortgages is the Federal National Mortgage
Association, known as Fannie Mae, which resells them to investors. But Fannie
Mae has been reluctant to buy such unconventional mortgages. Acorn hopes that
large commitments like that of Nationsbank will help bring pressure on Fannie
Mae. Already, Nationsbank is talking about joining with Acorn’s Washington lobby.
Fannie was reluctant, but they got over it. They made an enormous
amount of money when they were “forced” to lower their standards. They weren’t
really forced. They liked being thrown into the briar patch.
Remember, this is 1992. In 1995, the CRA got revised and was made
tougher. Fannie and Freddie’s were required to buy more mortgages made to
low-income buyers. In 1995, President Clinton announced the 1996 Home Ownership
Strategy. Read
about it here. Go to the end of the document. It details all the activities
that would increase home ownership.
And it worked. Or something did. Correlation is not causation. The fact
that home ownership rates started to rise in 1995 doesn’t mean the policy
worked. But that was the goal of the policy and the stated activities related
to that goal (Making Financing More Available, Affordable, and Flexible) would
increase home ownership. Of course, you have to look at the data. You have to
show that financing did become more available, affordable, and flexible.
This 2001
paper by Josh Rosner makes the case pretty convincingly. But maybe I’m
biased. You tell me where Rosner goes wrong. He does have a lot of data.
Remember, this is 2001. Long before the important part of the subprime crisis.
I summarize the role of Fannie and Freddie’s increased willigness to
buy mortgages they wouldn’t have bought before, here.
I’m agnostic about their direct role in subprime. I don’t think they bought
very much of it. They bought a lot of subprime MBS. But maybe someone else
would have bought that anyway. It was awfully profitable for a while.
So my claim is that between 1995 (and maybe a little earlier) and
2001, there was a lot of government policy that pushed up the demand for
housing. Increases in demand usually increase prices. There are exceptions. If
supply is sufficiently elastic, the price increase can be minimal. But I
think it’s pretty clear that in some cities, supply was quite inelastic, for
both geographic reasons and zoning restrictions. So the push in demand helped
create the rise in prices you see in the graph.
It probably didn’t create the subprime crisis directly. But it doesn’t
have to in my story. In my story, the increase in demand (driven by housing
policy, somewhat well-intended (getting people into homes who couldn’t afford
them before), somewhat very nasty self-interested cronyism (NAR, NAHB, Fannie
and Freddie) pushed up the price of housing between 1995 and 2001.
Once the price of housing started rising dramatically, it became
profitable to bet on the rise continuing. So a lot of people, smart and stupid,
tried to ride that meteor as it shot upward. And that’s where the shadow
banking system and the low interest rates come in. The shadow bankers pumped
trillions into that market via all those innovative new assets (CDO’s, CDO
squared etc). They use borrowed money because they could. The lenders lent
the money because the
government had signaled that lenders would get made whole even when
the bets their loans financed were worthless. I learned part of that story
from a fine book called Bailout
Nation. I think you’ve heard of it. So moral hazard had something and maybe
a lot to do with the last part of the housing bubble and especially the
subprime part. But why did the moral hazard spend itself in the housing market
rather than somewhere else? That was because that market was rising nicely. But
why was it rising nicely. Animal spirits or government policy that kicked off
the madness? I think the government had a lot to do with it.
Here’s where my story is squishy. It’s not enough to say that demand
went up, so prices went up. You have to show that the magnitudes are
reasonable. You have to show the areas where Fannie and Freddie were most
active between 1995 and 2001 were the areas where price rose. I’ve seen one
paper that argues that Fannie and Freddie’s affordable housing goals
had a limited impact on providing liquidity. Could be. But it is hard to tease
out independent effects. I suspect this debate and empirical evidence will keep
going for a while. But it’s a reasonable debate. It’s not silly.
And yes, I know other countries had housing bubbles but didn’t have a
CRA or Fannie or Freddie. You can increase subsidies to home ownership without
having the same named entities. Again, it’s an empirical question. And I
certainly agree that monetary policy and the coddling of cronies in the shadow
banking system made the whole thing many times worse than it otherwise would
have been.
No comments:
Post a Comment