Yes, he did that, but way more he created an idea that was simple and that all policy makers could consider. It really was elementary. You understand that man makes bargains and this must be facilitated for an economy to prosper.
This idea has been challenged but has always won the day. Now no one really seriously argues otherwise. There are additional ideas that need also to be propagated in order to eliminate poverty but we have waited this long.
All knowledge is based on foundational conceptualizations. Adam Smith put our modern economy upon a rational basis that ended mercantilism as a dominant idea, although sadly we still see many still struggling for the advantage the same old ways.
Adam Smith Proved Ideas Matter
Smith, more than anyone else, laid the intellectual foundations of free trade and free markets
Lawrence W. Reed
July 20, 2015
http://fee.org/anythingpeaceful/detail/adam-smith-proved-ideas-matter
Adam Smith was baptized on June 5, 1723, in Kirkcaldy, Scotland. It’s not known for certain, but presumed that he was either born on that very day, or a day or two before. Whichever date it was, he entered a world that his reason and eloquence would later transform.
For 300 years before Smith, Western Europe was dominated by an economic system known as “mercantilism.” Though it provided for modest improvements in life and liberty over the feudalism that came before, it was a system rooted in error that stifled enterprise and treated individuals as pawns of the state.
Mercantilist thinkers believed that the world’s wealth was a fixed pie, giving rise to endless conflict between nations. After all, if you think there’s only so much and you want more of it, you’ve got to take it from someone else.
Mercantilists were economic nationalists. Foreign goods, they thought, were sufficiently harmful to the domestic economy so that government policy should be marshaled to promote exports and restrict imports. Instead of imported goods, they wanted exports to be paid for by foreigners in gold and silver. To the mercantilist, the precious metals were the very definition of wealth, especially to the extent that they piled up in the coffers of the monarch.
Because they had little sympathy for self-interest, the profit motive and the operation of prices, mercantilists wanted governments to bestow monopoly privileges upon a favored few. In Britain, the king even granted a protected monopoly over the production of playing cards to a particular, highly-placed noble.
Economics in the late 18th century was not yet a focused subject of its own, but rather a poorly organized compartment of what was known as “moral philosophy.” Smith’s first of two books, The Theory of Moral Sentiments, was published in 1759 when he held the chair of moral philosophy at Glasgow University. He was the first moral philosopher to recognize that the business of enterprise — and all the motives and actions in the marketplace that give rise to it — was deserving of careful, full-time study as a modern discipline of social science.
The culmination of his thoughts in this regard came in 1776. As American colonists were declaring their independence from Britain, Smith was publishing his own shot heard round the world, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, better known ever since as simply The Wealth of Nations.
Smith’s choice of the longer title is revealing in itself. Note that he didn’t set out to explore the nature and causes of the poverty of nations. Poverty, in his mind, was what happened when nothing happens, when people are idle by choice or force, or when production is prevented or destroyed. He wanted to know what brings the things we call material wealth into being, and why. It was a searching examination that would make him a withering critic of the mercantilist order.
Wealth was not gold and silver in Smith’s view. Precious metals, though reliable as media of exchange and for their own industrial uses, were no more than claims against the real thing. All of the gold and silver in the world would leave one starving and freezing if they couldn’t be exchanged for food and clothing. Wealth to the world’s first economist was plainly this: goods and services.
Whatever increased the supply and quality of goods and services,
lowered their price or enhanced their value made for greater wealth and
higher standards of living. The “pie” of national wealth isn’t fixed;
you can bake a bigger one by producing more.
Baking that bigger pie, Smith showed, results from investments in
capital and the division of labor. His famous example of the specialized
tasks in a pin factory demonstrated how the division of labor works to
produce far more than if each of us acted in isolation to produce
everything himself. It was a principle that Smith showed works for
nations precisely because it works for the individuals who make them up.
He was consequently an economic internationalist, one who
believes in the widest possible cooperation between peoples irrespective
of political boundaries. He was, in short, a consummate free trader at a
time when trade was hampered by an endless roster of counterproductive
tariffs, quotas and prohibitions.
Smith wasn’t hung up on the old mercantilist fallacy that more goods should be exported than imported. He exploded this “balance of trade” fallacy by
arguing that since goods and services constituted a nation’s wealth, it
made no sense for government to make sure that more left the country
than came in.
Self-interest, frowned upon for ages as acquisitive, anti-social
behavior, was celebrated by Smith as an indispensable spur to economic
progress. “It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or
the baker, that we can expect our dinner,” he wrote, “but from their
regard to their own interest.”
Moreover, self-interest was an unsurpassed incentive: “The natural
effort of every individual to better his own condition ... is so
powerful, that it is alone, and without any assistance, not only capable
of carrying on the society to wealth and prosperity, but of surmounting
a hundred impertinent obstructions with which the folly of human laws
too often encumbers its operations.”
In a free economy, he reasoned, no one can put a crown on his head
and command that others provide him with goods. To satisfy his own
desires, he must produce what others want at a price they can afford.
Prices send signals to producers so that they will know what to make
more of and what to provide less of. It wasn’t necessary for the king to
assign tasks and bestow monopolies to see that things get done. Prices
and profit would act as an “invisible hand” with far more efficiency
than any monarch or parliament. And competition would see to it that
quality is improved and prices are kept low.
Smith’s view of competition was undoubtedly shaped by the way he saw
the universities of his day, loaded with coddled, tenured professors
whose pay had little to do with their service to their pupils or the
public at large. While a student at Oxford in the 1740s, he observed the
lassitude of his professors who “had given up altogether even the
pretense of teaching.”
If it seems that Smith put much more faith in people and markets than
in kings and edicts, it’s because that’s precisely right. With
characteristic eloquence, he declared that “In the great chess-board of
human society, every single piece has a principle of motion of its own,
altogether different from that which the legislature might choose to
impress upon it.”
Smith displayed an understanding of government that eclipses that of
many citizens today when he wrote, “It is the highest impertinence and
presumption, therefore, in kings and ministers, to pretend to watch over
the economy of private people, and to restrain their expense . . . .
They are themselves always, and without any exception, the greatest
spendthrifts in the society. Let them look well after their own expense,
and they may safely trust private people with theirs. If their own
extravagance does not ruin the state, that of their subjects never
will.”
The ideas of Adam Smith exerted enormous influence before he died in
1790 and especially in the 19th century. America’s Founders were greatly
affected by his insights. The Wealth of Nations became required reading among men and women of ideas the world over.
A tribute to him more than any other individual, the world in 1900
was much freer and more prosperous than anyone imagined in 1776. The
march of free trade and globalization in our own time is further
testimony to the enduring legacy of Adam Smith. A think tank in Britain bears his name and seeks to make that legacy better known.
Ideas really do matter. They can change the world. Adam Smith proved
that in spades, and we are all immeasurably better off because of the
ideas he shattered and the ones he set in motion.
No comments:
Post a Comment