This is a long confused dissertation
on the subject of inflation which is nobodies concern at the present because it
is still largely non existent except among certain categories. The reality is that we are actually living
through a broad deflation masked by the occasional pricy item. Recall that the most important consumer goods
are operating against much the same price point as thirty years ago in exchange
for a steady increase in quality.
All electronics and clothing
comes under that argument and the prime driver of energy is presently enjoying
a last round of excessive pricing before they have to contend with cheap electrical
cars. Food is been presently also been
price pushed and every farmer is moving to exploit that window.
The fact is that an expanding
global market has put downward pressure on pricing for thirty years and the
financial collapse of 2008 has given us the cheapest possible money which is now
been aggressively used to expand global production.
Those pointing to the application
of money printing fail to recognize it is going to patch the losses brought on
with reckless lending from the preceding decade. That means the money is already spent. In the meantime the resultant recession has
dumped millions into the out of work category further suppressing wages which
the last time I checked is very deflationary.
This deflation will not end until
this overhang of foreclosed housing and surplus labor is reabsorbed. It could be done through a smart program in a
few months, but is likely to take years because of leadership incompetence. We need a Ronald Reagan able to do a couple
of simple things.
What’s Up with Inflation?
Warren C. Gibson
Inflation as measured by the Consumer Price Index (CPI) has been almost
nonexistent for several years, though it started creeping higher in the first
half of 2011. Yet many prices have been rising at double-digit percentage rates.
Are official figures trustworthy? And what of expectations? There is a great
deal of buzz right now about inflation but also talk of renewed
stagnation with the Fed’s QE2 program having ended in June. Could renewed
stagnation trigger enough deflation to counter inflation? Or might we get the
worst of both worlds—stagflation—as in the 1970s?
We can’t get anywhere with these questions until we agree on the
meaning of inflation. At one time the word referred to an increase in the money
supply. Over time it came to mean a general increase in prices, an unfortunate
turn of events not just because we lost the nice metaphor of an inflating
balloon, but also because the shift in meaning tended to obscure the
relationship between the two phenomena. Some free-market authors hold out for
the old definition, but I suggest this is wasted effort. In my classes I use
the phrases “price inflation” and “money inflation” to keep the distinction
alive without getting too sidetracked by semantics.
In 1970 Milton Friedman said, “[Price] inflation is always and
everywhere a monetary phenomenon.” This is not entirely true but understandable
because he was writing at a time when the causal relationship had nearly been
forgotten. We can have price inflation without money inflation when there is a
supply shock. An overthrow of the Saudi government, for example, might well
disrupt the flow of oil from that country. A surging oil price, because it is
so important to our economy, would likely pull up the price level with it. In
this situation the monetary authorities can help things by doing exactly
nothing—letting higher energy prices do the work of encouraging marginal users
to cut back. Supply shocks, as such one-time events are called, do not of
themselves generate sustained price increases and are therefore not classified
as inflation by some economists.
Price inflation of a mild sort can also happen as new and more
efficient payment systems are devised. When we acquire debit cards and credit
cards, we find it less necessary to hold a supply of money for our daily needs
or emergencies. We may reduce not just our currency holdings but also our
checking account balances. But money is always in someone’s possession, so an
aggregate decline in the demand to hold money results in faster spending, which
generates price inflation. Those higher prices motivate people to increase
their desired money holdings back to the previous level.
Expectations of future price inflation can also be a source of current
price inflation. There is a great deal of inertia in inflation expectations.
When there has been a long period of stability we tend to gloss over early
signs of inflation, and it takes a long time for people to realize that price
rises aren’t just temporary. Likewise, when prices have been rising steadily,
people are skeptical of deflationary (or disinflationary) developments. During
an inflationary period expectations can run ahead of the money supply. Thus
during the German hyperinflation of the 1920s people spent their money faster than
the authorities could print it, and almost until the end the authorities denied
that money printing was the root of price inflation, believing instead that
money creation should be stepped up.
Recently Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke said he was not worried about price
inflation because investors are currently paying a very low premium for
inflation-protected Treasury securities, adding, “The state of inflation
expectations greatly influences actual inflation.” Gerald O’Driscoll, well
known in free-market circles and a former Fed official, retorted that Bernanke “has the causation
precisely backwards” (TheFreemanOnline, Feb. 28). In fact the
causation runs both ways. Market participants try to figure out what the Fed will
do, and the Fed tries to figure out how it can influence expectations, and on
it goes, back and forth. But as in the stock market, expectations may turn out
to be wrong, and in the long run only the fundamentals matter.
What of the converse of the Friedman proposition? If there is money
inflation must there necessarily be price inflation? The first chart suggests
not. Price inflation got ahead of money inflation in about 1980, as Fed
Chairman Paul Volcker’s tight money policy did not at first overcome expectations.
But since 2008 the monetary base has exploded without any significant
price inflation. Why?
The Federal Reserve controls the monetary base, consisting of publicly
held currency plus commercial banks’ reserve accounts at the Fed (this is also
referred to as M1). The Fed increases the base when it purchases assets,
typically government securities, using newly created money. Commercial banks
then pyramid on top of the monetary base. A dollar of reserves can support up
to about ten dollars in new loans—a multiplier effect. In the 1950s M1 was
about 3.5 times the size of the monetary base. That multiplier declined sharply
after 2000, until, as the first chart shows, the monetary base raced ahead of
M1 money.
New money created by the Fed first goes to the bank accounts of the
parties such as bond dealers from whom the Fed buys assets. Typically banks
loan out most of that money because that’s how they seek profits. Bankers
normally consider reserves in excess of the level required by the Fed as idle assets,
which are to be avoided. Total reserves were around $2 billion until the crisis
of 2008, at which time they began to skyrocket. They now exceed $1,100 billion.
What motivated this huge increase? First, banks seem not to find a lot of
attractive lending opportunities at this time. Second, since 2008 the Fed has
been paying interest on reserves, currently a very modest 0.25 percent per
year.
About Those Reserves . . .
Now for the $64 trillion question: What if banks reverse course and
start deploying some of those idle reserves? Suppose they find good loan
opportunities and jumpstart the pyramiding process? If the M1 money multiplier
were to rebound from 0.8 to 1.6, where it stood just three years ago, assuming
no change in the monetary base, we would get about $2 trillion flooding into
markets. What could the Fed do to head off the price inflation that would
follow?
In the past the Fed might have opted to drain reserves by selling
Treasury securities. This would depress the price of those securities and raise
interest rates—not good for the economy and not good for the Treasury, which
counts on selling large quantities of new securities at low interest rates. The
Fed now has an alternative that could restrain price inflation by keeping
reserves in place. It could raise the interest it pays on reserves. This would
discourage banks from expanding their loan portfolios. This latter method can
be applied at a keystroke, in contrast to sales of Treasury securities, which
takes time. Still, we have to wonder if Bernanke and friends will apply the
brakes at just the right time. Given the dynamics of expectations and the
uncertain prospects for supply shocks, it will be a difficult trick to say the
least. Higher interest rates could wreak havoc on the federal budget. The
President’s budget proposal for FY 2012 sees net interest payments rising from
about $200 billion for FY 2011 to $928 billion for 2021. As always, the budget
is based on optimistic assumptions about tax revenue growth and spending
restraint. But it is also optimistic about interest rates. Higher rates could
drive interest expense much higher, and because so much outstanding federal
debt is of short duration, the effect might happen quickly.
Price Inflation: Mixed Signals
What of current price inflation? Is it really as low as the CPI
suggests? It depends where you look. House prices are way down, and housing is
part of the CPI. Homeowners are assumed to charge themselves rent, but lucky
for them that charge is down. This may be scant comfort to homeowners facing
increases in the prices of things they buy for cash, many of which are up.
The stock market has nearly doubled since the low of early 2009.
Commodity prices have been soaring. A recent 12-month period saw increases of
31 percent in crude oil, 79 percent in wheat, 166 percent in cotton, 98 percent
in rubber, 44 percent in copper, and 94 percent in silver. But natural gas
prices fell 23 percent, and olive oil (extra virgin, that is) is off 12
percent. Firms that process these raw materials into retail products typically
hedge their positions with futures contracts, but as those contracts expire
they will begin paying more for raw materials. Some of those increases are
already finding their way into retail prices.
Crude-oil prices spiked to $140 per barrel in 2008, then collapsed. But
in late May they again passed $100. A disruption in supplies of Middle East oil could send the price much higher, or a
return to stability could send them lower. No one knows. All we know is that
crude-oil price changes make their way very quickly into retail gasoline
prices. Truckers and others who are sensitive to fuel prices are adding fuel
surcharges to their rates. Other effects lag further behind. Should oil remain
above $100 we can certainly expect more retail price increases.
Wholesale price increases on foodstuffs have already affected retail
prices. The Food and Agricultural Organization’s world Food Price Index has
risen dramatically, as the second chart shows. This is becoming a crisis in
poor countries, where food takes a large share of personal income. Prices are
beginning to rise in the United
States as well. Hershey, for example,
announced a 10 percent increase across the board, citing increased raw material
and transportation costs. The Agriculture Department is projecting a 5 percent
price increase this year for a basket of common food items (basics, not
chocolate).
What about other retail prices? Walmart CEO Bill Simon, who ought to
know, recently said price inflation is “going to be serious.” The news media
are full of articles about inflation. The last big U.S. inflation was in the
1970s, but should it heat up we can expect the younger generation to catch on
fast—and for expectations to begin to run with or ahead of price increases.
What’s Ahead
Inflation hawks are inside the gates of the Fed. Kansas City Fed
president Thomas Hoenig recently blamed the Fed’s highly accommodative policy
for rapidly increasing global food prices and called for an increase in the
target Fed funds interest rate to 1 percent in a “fairly short period of time.”
Presidents of the Philadelphia , Richmond ,
and Dallas branches are also considered hawkish
on inflation but are opposed by New
York Fed president William C. Dudley and by Bernanke
himself. Bernanke recently testified that food prices have risen in all
currencies, not just the dollar, as if this exonerated the Fed. Markets, after
all, are globally connected.
Could China export
inflation to the United
States ? The Communist Party’s new five-year
plan is supposed to focus on the well-being of the common folk. This would mean
a reduction in the forced savings that have boosted Chinese export industries
and thus higher prices for Americans.
The U.S.
presidential election is next year, and the political business cycle is with us
as ever. The administration, aided and abetted by the Fed, will be doing all it
can to reduce unemployment before the election while keeping the lid on price
inflation. On the fiscal side there will be no significant budget cuts, which
nearly always have negative short-term consequences but benefits that accrue
only long after the election.
We would all do well to prepare ourselves, without going overboard, for
inflation. Personally, I’m bullish on cat food. Why not stock up on durable
goods? Savings accounts pay nothing, and you’re going to consume the stuff
anyway.
Stagflation, anyone?
No comments:
Post a Comment