When Socialism fails and when Capitalism fails, they fail for
precisely the same reason. The singular belief that top down command
and control actually works best when it is the least effective way of
optimizing impact. Neither have learned to operate at the community
level in terms of credit and wealth production. In fact the natural
instinct is quite the opposite until a crisis is induced in both
regimes and all variations of them.
The crash part may not even be dramatic. The USSR succumbed to a
persistent withdrawal of services from its increasingly suppressed
workers that continued for decades.
It there is one lesson to be learned during this past two decades, it
is that all levels of financial expansion can be and should be
managed at the local level with a working committee of individual
stakeholders who depend on success in their lending. This was the
secret of microlending.
Now imagine a stable community negotiating on behalf of its available
employables for terms rather than a union.
A Socialism for the
21st Century
Friday, 07 June 2013
00:00By Richard D Wolff,
Capitalism has stopped
"delivering the goods" for quite a while now, especially in
its older bases (Europe, North America and Japan). Real wage
stagnation, deepening wealth and income inequalities, unsustainable
debt levels and export of jobs have been prevailing trends in those
areas. The global crisis since 2007 only accelerated those trends. In
response, more has happened than Keynesianism returning to challenge
neoliberalism and critiques returning to challenge uncritical
celebrations of capitalism. Capitalism's development has raised a
basic question again: Whatalternative economic system might be
necessary and preferable for societies determined to do better than
capitalism? That old mole, socialism, has thus returned for
interrogation about its past to draw the lessons about its present
and future.
The Historical
Background of Socialism
Since the mid 19th
century, socialism has mostly been differentiated from capitalism in
two basic ways. Instead of capitalism's private ownership of means of
production (land, factories, offices, stores, machinery, etcetera),
socialism would transfer that ownership to the state as the
administrator for public, social or collective ownership. Instead of
capitalism's distribution of resources and products by means of
market exchange, socialism would substitute state central planning to
accomplish that distribution. Marxism was generally viewed as the
basic theoretical criticism of capitalism that went on to define and
justify a social transition from capitalism to socialism. Communism
was generally viewed as a distant, rather utopian stage of social
development beyond socialism wherein class differences would
disappear, the state would wither away as a social institution, work
activity would be transformed and distribution would be based purely
on need.
Before 1917, socialism
comprised both the critical analysis of capitalism and the
anti-capitalist programs promoted by various social movements, labor
unions, writers and political parties. They advocated transitions
from private toward state ownership of means of production, and from
market toward state-planned distribution. Socialism was stunningly
successful at winning hearts and minds; it spread quickly across the
globe. By 1917, a revolution in Russia enabled a new government to
replace the capitalism it had inherited with what it understood as
socialism. Bolshevik leaders thus moved to nationalize productive
property in industry and institute planning as hallmarks of the new
Union of Soviet Socialist Republics' (USSR's) economy.
Yet Soviet socialism
also changed and complicated the meaning of socialism in the world.
Beyond being a general theory and program of anti-capitalism,
socialism came also to be the label applied to what was said and done
in and by the USSR. This change had profound consequences. Socialists
around the world split into two wings or segments. [1] For
one wing, the evolving Soviet revolution was the realization of what
socialism had always sought. It therefore had to be defended at all
costs from capitalism's assaults. That wing increasingly defined
socialism as what the USSR did after 1917; Soviet socialism became
the model to be replicated everywhere.
The other wing
disagreed. Socialism's traditional theory and program did not need -
and ought not - to be adjusted to replicate what happened in the
USSR. Some in this wing criticized what the Bolsheviks did in the
USSR (particularly in terms of political freedoms and civil
liberties). Others believed that peaceful, nonrevolutionary and
electoral strategies were surer roads to socialism than Bolshevik
revolutionary politics. For them, "evolutionary" socialism
was a better road to take than revolutionary socialism. Classical
socialism, for this wing, was very different from what happened and
evolved in the USSR.
As debates between the
two wings intensified (especially in relation to World War I), the
admirers of the USSR changed their names from socialists to
communists. Where before these names had differentiated shorter-term
from longer-range goals of all socialists, after 1917 they
distinguished the more pro- from the more anti-Soviet socialists. The
USSR's survival and growing strength after 1917 (especially in
contrast to the Depression-wracked capitalist world of the 1930s),
its victory over Hitler in World War II, and then the successful
Chinese, Vietnamese and Cuban revolutions after 1945 brought the
Communist wing ever greater prominence in defining what socialism
meant.
Peculiar ambiguities
emerged. Sometimes, communism and socialism were treated synonymously
as the alternative to capitalism. Yet, leaders and
spokespersons of countries where self-described communists achieved
government power described their societies as "socialist"
and definitely not yet "communist." Socialists who were
critical of the USSR increasingly insisted on the importance of
differences between socialism and communism in theory and practice.
On the one hand, communists and socialists advocated the same basic
transitions from private to public ownership of means of production
and from markets to planning. On the other, they differed - often
sharply - over the speed, forms, and social conditions appropriate
for the transition from capitalism and over the role of civil
liberties and democratic freedoms once socialism was achieved.
The non-communist wing
of the socialist movement also grew in strength and influence after
1917. Large, mass-based socialist parties became regular, major
players in the electoral politics of many countries. Communist
parties played such roles less often. Sometimes communist and
socialist parties collaborated on shared objectives, and sometimes
differences created great enmity between them. Socialist parties
focused on electoral politics, increasingly rejecting revolutionary
strategies, tactics and language. The socialist wing largely
accommodated itself to the view that capitalism seemed securely in
place. The role for socialists was then to expose its flaws
(injustices, wastes and inefficiencies) and struggle politically to
impose governmental rules, constraints and interventions that would
impose "a human face" on capitalism. Socialists thus
focused on obtaining redistributive tax structures,
government-provided social safety nets and state-regulated markets.
In many countries, the socialists became the more or less accepted
mass-based left that favored a state-regulated, social-welfare
capitalism. Opposing the socialists was a basic right that favored
less state regulation, a capitalism in which the private capitalist
sector was dominant.
Toward the end of the
20th century, the relationship between the socialist and communist
wings altered drastically. With the collapse of the USSR and its
Eastern European allies in 1989, and following strategic shifts
inside the People's Republic of China, the growth of the communist
wing of the socialist movement reversed into sharp decline. The
Communists had established socialisms - based on state ownership of
industrial enterprises and central planning - that had shown
spectacular rates of economic growth and exemplary advances in the
standards of living for the mass of their citizens. However, they had
not been able to create the broader social conditions needed to
sustain that growth, to simultaneously protect themselves from a
hostile capitalist world, and all the while to retain the ideological
and political support of their countries' populations. When serious
crises hit them in the late 1980s, few social forces proved able or
willing to save or rebuild the systems that the communists had
constructed. Worse still, those systems' speedy conversions into
varying forms of monopoly capitalism and corrupted politics raised
further disquieting questions about what the systems of "actually
existing socialisms" really had been.
At first, the
socialist wing largely replaced a declining communism to become the
dominant contemporary form and definition of socialism. However, the
global resurgence of neoliberal capitalism after 1970 eventually
weakened support for the socialist wing, although not as effectively
as had happened earlier to the communist wing. Neoliberal ideologues
portrayed the collapse of the USSR and Eastern Europe as proof
positive that the long battle between capitalism, on the one hand,
and socialism or communism, on the other, had been definitively "won"
by the former. To remain a communist or even a socialist, in their
traditional senses, was portrayed as a sign of atavistic, antiquarian
self-delusion. History had rendered its verdict; it was final; and
there was no appeal. Not only had the USSR and its Eastern European
allies collapsed, but their subsequent gangster capitalism, crony
capitalism and other unattractive capitalisms further undermined
socialists' confidence in their earlier views of "actually
existing socialisms."
In the wake of these
post-1970s developments, many socialists around the world devolved
and merged into "progressive forces" within capitalism. For
them, socialism had stopped being an alternative to capitalism. There
simply was no such left alternative any more. Frustrated and deeply
disappointed, not a few of the former activists, militants and
supporters of both wings of traditional socialism disengaged from
politics altogether. For those ex-communists and ex-socialists who
did remain politically active, they were mostly "progressives
who recognized history's verdict" and devoted themselves to
making capitalism as equitable, democratic and generally humane as
possible. For some (for example, the Italian left) that meant
renouncing the names "socialist" and "communist"
in favor of others ("democrat" was especially popular).
Then history suddenly
mocked and undid the so-called verdict that had allegedly condemned
socialism and communism to the status of passé fashions. In the
global economic meltdown that began in 2007, capitalism "hit the
fan." Its extreme instability was exposed. Capitalism's utter
dependence on the state (to rescue it from crisis) was all the more
ironic and telling given the previous decades during which neoliberal
ideologues had endlessly vilified the state and called for its
drastic reduction. Capitalism's gross injustices were underscored as
its crisis victimized the many (jobless, homeless, etcetera) while
bailing out the few. Capitalists' control of the state was likewise
highlighted as it provided "recovery" for the few while
imposing austerity on the many.
History suddenly
reminded people that capitalism's contradictions, flaws and
injustices were what had generated socialism and communism in the
past. Those same qualities had never been overcome. When they
exploded into view again in 2007, similar critical movements and
upsurges were regenerated. Names and nuances would be different (such
as the "indignados" of Spain or the "occupiers"
of Wall Street, and much else). New parties would arise (e.g.,
"anti-capitalist" or "left"). New alternatives to
capitalism would emerge and show significant theoretical and
strategic importance. In all cases, however, their resemblances and
debts to the classical traditions of socialism and communism would be
no more difficult to see than their differences.
Traditional socialism,
in both of its major wings, was remarkably successful up to the
1970s. Its theoretical formulations (Marxist and non-Marxist,
critical and programmatic) and its institutional embodiments in
social movements, labor unions and parties (ruling as well as
oppositional) were powerful agents of that success. However,
socialism's global spread was checked after the 1970s. Former
Communist parties disappeared or lost influence in most countries.
Many socialist parties enhanced their accommodations to capitalism by
tolerating or even supporting first neoliberalism and then, since
2009, government austerity policies. The last 30 years also witnessed
the sharply reduced presence of explicitly socialist and Marxist
perspectives within many cultural domains. Adherence to those
perspectives fell correspondingly.
In short, some agents
of socialism's extraordinary global expansion across the century
before the 1970s morphed into obstacles and barriers to further
success. Likewise, socialism's enemies often found the resources and
the ways to slow, stop or reverse its progress. In any case,
socialism's history provides key raw materials for making the changes
needed now to fashion a socialism for the 21st century. Its past
achievements and failures, when faced honestly, are informing a new
socialism capable of moving beyond a capitalism riddled with
environmental as well as economic crises as it deepens profoundly
divisive and unsustainable inequalities.
What to Do Now
A new socialism for
the 21st century begins by assessing the limits of classical
socialism. That assessment's priority focus is not external
(how others hindered socialism's progress) - but rather
internal. Where socialists were responsible for their own
difficulties, there they can make significant changes. Serious
self-criticism might begin by questioning classical socialism's
definition of its chief tasks as changing (1) the ownership of
productive property from private to public and the distribution of
productive inputs and outputs from market to planning. These were
changes at the macro level of society, far removed from most people's
daily, micro-level lives. Many socialists believed that macro-level
transitions would determine similar micro-level transitions. Shifting
from capitalist (private) to socialist (collective) productive
property ownership and from market to planning systems of
distribution would cause parallel transitions from capitalist to
socialist individuals in their personalities and in their daily work,
home and community lives.
Where communists
achieved government power, they made many of traditional socialism's
prescribed macro changes. As a result, genuine benefits accrued at
the micro-level in the forms of much improved job security and wages
and much improved access to education, housing and medical care.
Where socialists gained governmental power, they made parallel
(albeit slower and more modest) macro changes in the same direction,
with corresponding benefits for the micro level. The changes and
resulting benefits won for communists and socialists the considerable
supports they enjoyed across most of the 20th century. At the same
time, the political power concentrated at the macro level (and
institutionalized in the party and the state) and narrow ideological
conformity provoked considerable criticism and opposition over much
the same period.
But neither the
macro-level changes nor the micro-level benefits ended the
exploitative employer-employee relationship that defines the
capitalist workplace. At that micro-level, employed workers still
used their brains and muscles to produce outputs whose values
exceeded the values of what they obtained in return as real wages. In
some communist countries, that value relationship was denominated in
the administered prices set by central planners. In most countries,
the value relationship was denominated in market prices. In either
case, what matters is the difference between what workers added in
production to the value to the raw materials, tools, and equipment
used up in production, and the value of their wages. That difference
(the "surplus" in Marx's theory or "net revenue,"
"profit" and other terms in other theories) continued to be
appropriated and distributed by persons other than those workers
nearly everywhere that socialists or communists shaped economies.
True, the surplus-appropriators could be state officials (e.g.,
commissars) rather than privately elected boards of directors, or
perhaps they were heavily state-regulated private boards, but in any
case, they exploited the surplus- producers precisely as
Marx specified in his Capital. In simplest terms, in actually
existing socialism and communism, the workers who produced the
surplus continued to be excluded from appropriating and distributing
it.
A parallel from
slavery may prove instructive here. Critics of slavery often defined
their objectives as improving slave conditions: achieving better
diets, clothing, housing, integrity of slave families and so on.
Other critics took a very different approach: they demanded abolition
of slavery. Socialists and communists, who often began as
abolitionists in their relation to capitalist exploitation, evolved
over the last century into advocates of the improvement of workers'
conditions while leaving intact the workplace relationship of
employer and employee. Communists, in effect, substituted state for
private capitalism, whereas the socialists stressed state-regulated
versus private (relatively less regulated) capitalism. Workers got
better working conditions where communists and socialists were
powerful, but they did not get an end to exploitation and all its
social effects. [2]
A socialism for the
21st century must include and stress the importance of micro-level
social transformation at the base of society in the workplace. Ending
exploitation in workplaces is that transformation. Instead of workers
producing surpluses for others to appropriate and distribute, they
must now do that for themselves collectively. They must become their
own board of directors. Ending workplace exploitation means that
non-workers, whether private individuals or state officials, can no
longer appropriate or distribute workers' surpluses. As "producer
cooperatives" or "democratized enterprises" (among
other names), such transformed workplaces represent a priority goal
of a new socialism. That socialism stresses the micro-level
transformation of society - the end of exploitation wherever people
work - as the necessary companion or counterpart to the
traditional macro-focus on property ownership and distribution
mechanisms. The macro and micro components of socialism would both
become equally necessary, conditions of each other's existence,
mutually reinforcing as well as mutually dependent. Neither will be
viewed or treated by policy as determinant of the other. Both will
shape one another much as they both shape and are shaped by the
larger social and natural contexts.
Such a socialism for
the 21st century situates the workers - the majority - as key
micro-level agents of its project and of the new society being
established. Workers will transform their factories, offices and
stores into producers' cooperatives or what are increasingly
called worker self-directed enterprises (WSDEs). [3] They
will likewise defend them both from regression back to capitalist
enterprises and from subordination to any state or party apparatus.
Workers will operate their enterprises as the continuing core of the
transition from capitalism to socialism. As their own boards of
directors, workers will collectively appropriate and distribute the
surpluses they produce. They will thereby have replaced capitalists.
Workers' democratic self-government in the workplace will then have
superseded capitalism's undemocratic organization of the workplace.
Other social
institutions formerly dependent on receiving distributions of
capitalist surpluses from the appropriators will then be dependent
instead on workers directing their own enterprises and thus
distributing their own surpluses. Government revenue, for example, to
the extent it depends on taxes on enterprise surpluses, would then
flow from (and hence be responsive to) workers in their capacity as
enterprise self-directors. The state would then become directly and
financially dependent on the organized (in and by their enterprises)
workers in a way and to a degree unequalled in human history.
Correspondingly, the risks of power passing from the mass of people
in their residences and workplaces to a state bureaucracy - a serious
problem for traditional socialism - would be reduced.
When the workers
collectively and democratically distribute the surpluses they
produce, they will have a powerful influence on how the society's
surpluses are distributed. That influence will likely work against
the sorts of extreme inequality in the distribution of personal
income typical of capitalist societies. For example, workers in WSDEs
will not likely distribute wildly disproportionate shares of the
surplus in the forms of huge salaries for top executives while the
mass of employees barely get by. There will be little need for
redistributive tax systems because enterprises' initial distributions
of income - both as individual wages and as distributed shares of the
surplus - from WSDEs will be far more egalitarian. The long history
of capitalism's failed efforts to avoid highly unequal distributions
of wealth, income, political power and cultural access can finally be
overcome by a transition to a non-exploitation-based economic system.
The socialism for the
21st century sketched above combines the traditional macro-focus on
socialized productive property and planning with the micro-focus on a
democratization of workplaces. Removing workplace exploitation
represents a major step toward achievement of the French Revolution's
goals: liberté, égalité and fraternité. Capitalism took some
steps but prevented others. Its spokespersons and defenders forever
celebrated (and still do) a democracy that is rigidly excluded from
the system's enterprises (where most adults spend most of their
active lives). Capitalism's history repeatedly demonstrates that the
absence of democracy inside enterprises undermines it elsewhere in
society (or else yields caricatures, as in "democratic"
elections corrupted by the system's economic inequalities).
By including the
democratization of enterprises - as embodied in WSDEs - a 21st
century socialism can also recapture, renew and refocus the hope,
commitment and passions inaugurated in the French Revolution.
Revolutionary upsurges have punctuated capitalism ever since despite
all the efforts of modern societies finally to extinguish them. A
socialism for the 21st century can build on the centuries-long
interest in communal and cooperative work organizations among both
religious and secular communities. It can partner with present-day
cooperative institutions whose multiplicity and potential have been
celebrated by Gar Alperovitz. [4]
Imagine democratic
enterprises interacting with democratic residential communities -
economic and political democracies reinforcing one another and making
one another real, not merely formal. Jointly they would co-determine
how society functions and changes. That vision and goal animates a
socialism for the 21st century. It builds upon, while also critically
departing from, traditional socialism's contradictory history. It
embodies the aspirations of all those who contemplate the present in
the spirit of knowing that we can do better than capitalism.
Endnotes
1. Of
course, some individuals and some parties articulated combinations,
variations and even departures from these two basic wings of
socialism, but they were quite secondary in terms of their historical
importance and social impacts.
2. For
a full presentation and documentation of this argument, with special
reference to Soviet socialism, see Stephen Resnick and Richard
Wolff, Class Theory and History: Capitalism and Communism in the
USSR, New York and London: Routledge Publishers, 2002.
3. For
a detailed elaboration of WSDEs, see Richard Wolff, Democracy at
Work: A Cure for Capitalism. Chicago: Haymarket Books, 2012.
4. See,
for examples, his America Beyond Capitalism: Reclaiming Our
Wealth, Our Liberty, and Our Democracy. Tacoma, Maryland: Democracy
Collaborative Press, 2011, and his What Then Must We Do? White
River Junction, Vermont: Chelsea Green Publishing, 2013.
I like Prof. Wolff a lot, especially his suggestion for worker co-ops.
ReplyDeleteIt's a bit of a stretch to see how this encomium to socialism furthers the purpose of "Terra Forming Terra". Nevertheless, it is, sadly, yet another in a seemingly endless stream of economicslly illiterate tirades against a strawman, capitalism. The capitalism the author attacks would more accurately be termed Fascism - a government, corporate oligopoly, which is much more akin to the socialism the author is so infatuated with, than to pure capitalism, i.e., free market capitalism, which is simply a huge network of exchanges, entered voluntarily by all contracting parties for mutual benefit in accordance with their own values at the time of contracting. All socialisms, communism, crony capitalism (Fascism), by contrast, are at their core, systems of state dominated coercion. Everyone must either act in accordance with dictates of the State or starve, go to prison or get a bullet to the back of the head. The author's big yawner is the repetitive reliance on alleged "exploitative" capitalism taking the "surplus" value (profit) of the workers. Would the author then, also require workers return a portion of their wages for businesses that fail as clearly they would have been receiving more than what they contributed. I won't hold my breath. More importantly, the author's economic ignorance of free market functioning overlooks that businesses must compete for labour services thus driving up wages. Then there are the factual allegations that just aren't so. Look at one of his most obvious howlers, that "Traditional socialism, in both of its major wings, was remarkably successful up to the 1970s. Its theoretical formulations (Marxist and non-Marxist, critical and programmatic) and its institutional embodiments in social movements, labor unions and parties (ruling as well as oppositional) were powerful agents of that success." So, in short, he claims all socialisms were successful until the 1970's. I don't know. Somehow that seems to conflict with the tens of millions who died of starvation in Mao's Chins, or the millions who perished in Stalin's gulag and his deliberate starving to death of over 10 million Kulaks. Lord Acton's observation that "Power corrupts and absolute power corrupts absolutely" is much more accurate than the Marxian notion that by giving absolute power to the (Communist) State, those Communists holding the reins of power will be magically transformed into letting go such power to usher in a stateless communism. This article could have salvaged some credence had it properly identified free market capitalists as an alternative to the Fascistic crony capitalism it wrongly identifies as "Capitalism". A little familiarity with "Austrian" economics, a la Mises, Rothbard, Hoppe, etc. may open the mind of this author to socialism's inherent fallacies. That the author, in the end, turns to Syndicalism (worker owned coops) to salvage socialism reveals he is equally uninformed of Syndicalism's impossibility of improving the worker's lot. For more on Syndicalism, see one of Ludwig von Mises masterworks, Socialism.
ReplyDelete