Simply put, the power of banking is explicitly the power to create money and to place it to account.
For that reason alone it needs to be progressively localized. I go
so far as asserting that it needs to be available even at the local
model community level as a core operating tool. It certainly need to
be available wherever capital is already concentrated as in the State
house, the big city council and were as in Scotland, reckless banking
has wiped out the capital base available to local lending.
In fact the centralizing of banking authority is a retrogressive
activity that needs to be avoided however logical it appears.
Iceland did it right by quickly reinstating middle class credit and
nationalizing the local banking system.
In Scotland, they are relearning the power of local banking after
watching it all swept away.
Ensuring Scottish
Sovereignty: Exploring the Public Bank Option
Posted: 12/07/2012
2:42 pm
Ellen Brown
The Royal Bank of
Scotland (RBS) and the Bank of Scotland have been pillars of
Scotland's economy and culture for over three centuries. So when
the RBS was nationalized by the London-based UK government following
the 2008 banking crisis, and the Bank of Scotland was acquired by the
London-based Lloyds Bank, it came as a shock to the Scots. They
no longer owned their oldest and most venerable banks.
Another surprise turn
of events was the triumph of the Scottish National Party (SNP) in the
2011 Scottish parliamentary election. Scotland is still part of
the United Kingdom, but it has had its own parliament since 1999,
similar to U.S. states. The SNP has rallied around the call for
independence from the UK since its founding in 1934, but it was a
minority party until the 2011 victory, which gave it an overall
majority in the Scottish Parliament.
Scottish independence
is now on the table. A bill has been introduced to the Scottish
Parliament with the intention of holding a referendum on the issue in
2014.
Arguments in favor of
independence include that it will allow the Scottish people to make
decisions for Scotland themselves, on such contentious issues as
having nuclear weapons in their seas and being part of NATO. They
can also directly access the profits from the North Sea oil off
Scotland's coast.
Arguments against
independence include that Scotland's levels of public spending (which
are higher than in the rest of the UK) would be difficult to sustain
without raising taxes. North Sea oil revenues will
eventually decline.
One way budgetary
problems might be relieved would be for Scotland to have its own
publicly-owned bank, one that served the interests of the Scottish
people. True economic sovereignty means having control over the
national currency, credit and debt.
The Public Bank Option
It was in that
context that I was asked to give a presentation on public banking
at RSA Scotland (the Royal Society of Arts) in Edinburgh on Nov. 22.
Among other attendees were a special adviser and a civil servant from
the Scottish government. The presentation was followed by one
by public sector consultant Ralph Leishman, director of 4-consulting,
who made the public bank option concrete with specific proposals
fitting the Scottish context. He suggested that the
Scottish Investment Bank (SIB) be licensed as a depository bank, on
the model of the state-owned Bank of North Dakota. Lively debate
followed.
The SIB is a division
of Scottish Enterprise (SE), a government economic development
body. SE encourages economic development, enterprise, innovation
and investment in business, which is achieved by the SIB through the
Scottish Loan Fund. As noted in a September 2011
government report titled "Government Economic
Strategy":
"[S]ecuring affordable
finance remains a considerable challenge... Evidence shows that
while many large companies have significant cash holdings or can
access capital markets directly, for most Small and Medium-sized
companies bank lending remains the key source of finance. Unblocking
this is key to helping the recovery gain traction."
The limitation of a
public loan fund is that the money can be lent only to one borrower
at a time. Invested as capital in a bank, on the other hand,
public funds can be leveraged into nearly ten times that sum in
loans. Liquidity to cover the loans is provided by deposits,
which remain in the bank available to the depositors. Any
shortage in liquidity can be covered by borrowing at low interest
from other banks or the money market. As observed by Kurt von
Mettenheim, et al., in a 2008 report titled "Government
Banking: New Perspectives on Sustainable Development and Social
Inclusion from Europe and South America" (at page 196): "[I]n
terms of public policy, government banks can do more for less: Almost
ten times more if one compares cash used as capital reserves by banks
to other policies that require budgetary outflows."
Leishman stated that
the SIB now has investment funds of 23.2 million pounds from the
Scottish government. Rounding this to 25 million pounds, a
public depository bank could have sufficient capital to back 250
million pounds in loans. For deposits to cover the loans, the
Scottish Government has 125 million pounds on deposit with private
banks, currently earning little or no interest. Adding just 14
percent of the General Fund cash and cash equivalent reserves held by
Scotland's local governments would provide another 125 million
pounds, reaching the needed 250 million pounds, with six times that
sum in local government revenues to spare.
The Model of the
Bank of North Dakota
My assignment was to
show what the government could do with its own bank, following the
model of the Bank of North Dakota (BND). on the Saturday
following the RSA event, The Scotsman published an
article by Alf Young that summarized the issues and
possibilities so well that I'm taking the liberty of abstracting from
it here.
North Dakota is
currently the only U.S. state to own its own depository bank. The
BND was founded in 1919 by Norwegian and other immigrants,
determined, through their Non-Partisan League, to stop rapacious Wall
Street money men foreclosing on their farms.
All state revenues
must be deposited with the BND by law. The bank pays no bonuses,
fees or commissions; does no advertising; and maintains no branches
beyond the main office in Bismarck. The bank offers cheap credit
lines to state and local government agencies. There are
low-interest loans for designated project finance. The BND
underwrites municipal bonds, funds disaster relief and supports
student loans. It partners with local commercial banks to
increase lending across the state and pays competitive interest rates
on state deposits. For the past ten years, it has been paying a
dividend to the state, with a quite small population of about
680,000, of some $30 million (18.7 million pounds) a year.
Young writes:
"Intriguingly,
North Dakota has not suffered the way much of the rest of the U.S. --
indeed much of the western industrialized world -- has, from the
banking crash and credit crunch of 2008; the subsequent economic
slump; and the sovereign debt crisis that has afflicted so many. With
an economy based on farming and oil, it has one of the lowest
unemployment rates in the U.S., a rising population and a state
budget surplus that is expected to hit $1.6 billion by next July. By
then North Dakota's legacy fund is forecast to have swollen to around
$1.2 billion.
With that kind of
resilience, it's little wonder that twenty American states, some
of them close to bankruptcy, are at various stages of legislating to
form their own state-owned banks on the North Dakota model.
There's a long-standing tradition of such institutions elsewhere too.
Australia had a publicly-owned bank offering credit for
infrastructure as early as 1912. New Zealand had one operating in the
housing field in the 1930s. Up until 1974, the federal government in
Canada borrowed from the Bank of Canada, effectively interest-free.
... From our western
perspective, we tend to forget that, globally, around 40 per cent
of banks are already publicly owned, many of them concentrated in the
BRIC economies, Brazil, Russia, India and China."
Banking is not just a
market good or service. It is a vital part of societal
infrastructure, which properly belongs in the public sector. By
taking banking back, local governments could regain control of
that very large slice (up to 40 percent) of every public budget that
currently goes to interest charged to finance investment programs
through the private sector.
Recent academic
studies by von Mettenheim et al., and Andrianova et
al. show that countries with high degrees of government
ownership of banking have grown much faster in the last decade than
countries where banking is historically concentrated in the private
sector. Government banks are also less corrupt
and, surprisingly, have been more profitable in recent
years than private banks.
Young concluded his
article:
"As we left
Thursday's seminar, I asked another member of the audience, someone
with more than thirty years' experience as a corporate financier,
whether the concept of a publicly-owned bank has any chance of
getting off the ground here. 'I've no doubt it will happen,' came the
surprise response. 'When I look at the way our collective
addiction to debt has ballooned in my lifetime, I'd even say it's
inevitable.'"
The Scots are full of
surprises, and independence is in their blood. Recall the heroic
battles of William Wallace and Robert the Bruce memorialized by
Hollywood in the Academy Award-winning movie Braveheart.
Perhaps the Scots will blaze a trail for economic sovereignty in the
EU, just as the North Dakotans did in the U.S. A publicly-owned
bank could help Scotland take control of its own economic destiny, by
avoiding unnecessary debt to a private banking system that has
become a burden to the economy rather than a pillar in its support.
In my experience Govt institutions are not trailblazers to better finance, in fact they almost invariably lead to a decline in returns that always needs topping up by the taxpayer. The Bank of NZ comes instantly to mind, handed over to the incoming National Govt by the Labour Govt and instantly needing an injection of a billion dollars before being sold to the Australians. Air NZ would be another classic example.
ReplyDeleteThe problem we have is that private banks were not allowed to go broke, leading to a prolonged depression that will be with us until Govts have printed enough money to expunge the debt. A lifetime of misery for the next generation.