Once again we continue to
dither as the USA
economy actually contracts as it must do if the army of unemployed loses their
benefits and completely cease to be actively involved in the economy.
As I stated at the beginning
of this crisis in 2008, it is critical to restore the housing market first by a
resetting of the foreclosure laws to permit an immediate disposal of the entire
foreclosed inventory through underwriting the borrowers properly on a staged
recovery loan. Second, we must do as
described here with the creation of as many state owned banks as can be drummed
up. It will not end the disaster in California but it will
sharply reduce it and set it on the road to recovery.
I grieve that this is not
been done and it is a measure of the sheer incompetence of the bankers and
other such folks presently in charge. I
cannot even blame the president because he would have to be intellectually
superior to his advisors in matter of economics and that was never possible.
As we have now learned,
throwing money at the banks whose practices demolished their customers is an
utter waste of time. Throwing money at
the customers has a far better chance.
At this point the bankers are likely underwriting the Chinese bubble
with all this cheap money instead of creating creditworthy customers in the USA .
Why QE2 Failed: The Money All Went Offshore
By Ellen Brown
URL of this article: www.globalresearch.ca/index.php?context=va&aid=25566
Global Research, July 9, 2011
On June 30, QE2 ended with a whimper. The Fed’s second round of
“quantitative easing” involved $600 billion created with a computer keystroke for the purchase of long-term
government bonds. But the government never actually got the money, which
went straight into the reserve accounts of banks, where it still sits today.
Worse, it went into the reserve accounts of FOREIGN banks, on which the Federal
Reserve is now paying 0.25% interest.
Before QE2 there was QE1, in which the Fed bought $1.25 trillion in
mortgage-backed securities from the banks. This money too remains in bank
reserve accounts collecting interest and dust. The Fed reports that the
accumulated excess reserves of depository institutions now total
nearly $1.6 trillion.
Interestingly, $1.6 trillion is also the size of the federal deficit
– a deficit so large that some members of Congress are threatening to force a
default on the national debt if it isn’t corrected soon.
So here we have the anomalous situation of a $1.6 trillion hole in the
federal budget, and $1.6 trillion created by the Fed that is now sitting idle
in bank reserve accounts. If the intent of “quantitative easing” was to
stimulate the economy, it might have worked better if the money earmarked for
the purchase of Treasuries had been delivered directly to the Treasury.
That was actually how it was done before 1935, when the law was changed to
require private bond dealers to be cut into the deal.
The one thing QE2 did for the taxpayers was to reduce the interest tab
on the federal debt. The long-term bonds the Fed bought on the open
market are now effectively interest-free to the government, since the Fed
rebates its profits to the Treasury after deducting its
costs.
But QE2 has not helped the anemic local credit market, on which
smaller businesses rely; and it is these businesses that are largely
responsible for creating new jobs. In a June 30 article in the Wall
Street Journal titled “Smaller Businesses Seeking Loans Still Come Up Empty,”
Emily Maltby reported that business owners rank access to capital as the most
important issue facing them today; and only 17% of smaller businesses said they
were able to land needed bank financing.
How QE2 Wound Up in Foreign Banks
Before the Banking Act of 1935, the government was able to borrow
directly from its own central bank. Other countries followed that policy
as well, including Canada , Australia , and New Zealand ; and they prospered as
a result. After 1935, however, if the U.S. central bank wanted to buy
government securities, it had to purchase them from private banks on the “open
market.” Former Fed Chairman Marinner Eccles wrote in support of an act to remove that requirement that it
was intended to keep politicians from spending too much. But all the law
succeeded in doing was to give the bond-dealer banks a cut as
middlemen.
Worse, it caused the Fed to lose control of where the money went.
Rather than buying more bonds from the Treasury, the banks that got the cash
could just sit on it or use it for their own purposes; and that is apparently
what is happening today.
In carrying out its QE2 purchases, the Fed had to follow
standard operating procedure for “open market operations”: it took secret bids
from the 20 “primary dealers” authorized to sell securities to
the Fed and accepted the best offers. The problem was that 12 of these
dealers – or over half -- are U.S.-based branches of foreign banks (including
BNP Paribas, Barclays, Credit Suisse, Deutsche Bank, HSBC, UBS and others); and
they evidently won the bids.
The fact that foreign banks got the money was established in a June
12 post on Zero Hedge by Tyler Durden (a pseudonym), who
compared two charts: the total cash holdings of foreign-related banks in the U.S.,
using weekly Federal Reserve data; and the total reserve balances held at Federal Reserve banks,
from the Fed’s statement ending the week of June 1. The charts showed
that after November 3, 2010, when QE2 operations began, total bank reserves
increased by $610 billion. Foreign bank cash reserves increased in lock
step, by $630 billion -- or more than the entire QE2.
In a June 27 blog, John Mason, Professor of Finance at Penn State
University and a former
senior economist at the Federal Reserve, wrote:
In essence, it appears as if much of the monetary stimulus generated by
the Federal Reserve System went into the Eurodollar market. This is all part of
the “Carry Trade” as foreign branches of an American bank could borrow dollars
from the “home” bank creating a Eurodollar deposit. . . .
Cash assets at the smaller [U.S. ] banks remained relatively
flat . . . . Thus, the reserves the Fed was pumping into the banking system
were not going into the smaller banks. . . .
[B]usiness loans continue to “tank” at the smaller banking
institutions. . . .
The real lending by commercial banks is not taking place in the United States .
The lending is taking place off-shore, underwritten by the Federal Reserve
System and this is doing little or nothing to help the American economy grow.
Tyler Durden concluded:
. . . [T]he only beneficiary of the reserves generated were US-based
branches of foreign banks (which in turn turned around and funnelled the cash
back to their domestic branches), a shocking finding which explains . . . why
US banks have been unwilling and, far more importantly, unable to
lend out these reserves . . . .
. . . [T]he data above proves beyond a reasonable doubt why there has
been no excess lending by US banks to US borrowers: none of the cash ever
even made it to US banks! . . . This also resolves the mystery of the broken
money multiplier and why the velocity of money has imploded.
Well, not exactly. The fact that the QE2 money all wound up in
foreign banks is a shocking finding, but it doesn’t seem to be the reason banks
aren’t lending. There were already $1 trillion in excess reserves sitting
idle in U.S.
reserve accounts, not counting the $600 billion from QE2.
According to Scott Fullwiler, Associate Professor of Economics at Wartburg College , the money multiplier model is
not just broken but is obsolete. Banks do not lend based on what they
have in reserve. They can borrow reserves as needed after making
loans. Whether banks will lend depends rather on (a)
whether they have creditworthy borrowers, (b) whether they have sufficient
capital to satisfy the capital requirement, and (c) the cost of funds – meaning
the cost to the bank of borrowing to meet the reserve requirement, either from
depositors or from other banks or from the Federal Reserve.
Setting Things Right
Whatever is responsible for causing the local credit crunch, trillions
of dollars thrown at Wall Street by Congress and the Fed haven’t fixed the
problem. It may be time for local governments to take matters into their
own hands. While we wait for federal lawmakers to get it right, local
credit markets can be revitalized by establishing state-owned banks, on the
model of the Bank of North Dakota
(BND). The BND services the liquidity needs of local banks and keeps
credit flowing in the state. For more information, see here and here.
Concerning the gaping federal deficit, Congressman Ron Paul has an excellent idea: have the Fed simply write off the
federal securities purchased with funds created in its quantitative easing
programs. No creditors would be harmed, since the money was generated out
of thin air with a computer keystroke in the first place. The government
would just be canceling a debt to itself and saving the interest.
As for “quantitative easing,” if the intent is to stimulate the
economy, the money needs to go directly into the purchase of goods and
services, stimulating “demand.” If it goes onto the balance sheets of
banks, it may stop there or go into speculation rather than local lending -- as
is happening now. Money that goes directly to the government, on the
other hand, will be spent on goods and services in the real economy, creating
much-needed jobs, generating demand, and rebuilding the tax base. To make
sure the money gets there, the 1935 law forbidding the Fed to buy Treasuries
directly from the Treasury needs to be repealed.
Ellen Brown is an attorney and president of the Public Banking
Institute, http://PublicBankingInstitute.org. In Web of Debt, her latest of eleven books, she shows how the
power to create money has been usurped from the people, and how we can get it
back. Her websites are http://webofdebt.com and http://ellenbrown.com.
Real estate is about rents and until rents stabalize the bottom of the market will be unknown. This very important principle of value is either being ignored or is unknown by to many people.
ReplyDelete